First published at Left Voice
You write in
the introduction to your book, “Karl Marx’s Ecosocialism,” that for many years,
environmentalists—and even many Marxists—believed that Marx held a Promethean
viewpoint and that he was uncritical of the technology developed under
capitalism. Where did this idea come from, and why has it persisted until
recently?
One obvious reason is that Marx did
not finish “Capital.” Marx eagerly studied natural sciences in his late years,
but he was unable to fully integrate his new findings into “Capital.” Although
he planned to elaborate on ecological issues in volume 3, especially in
rewriting his theory of ground rent, he never made it very far, and even volume
2 of Capital was not published during his lifetime. Instead, Marx left only a
number of notebooks on natural sciences. Unfortunately, no one really paid
attention to them—and not many people read them today either—and they were not
even published for a long time, although now the “Marx-Engels-Gesamtausgabe”
(MEGA) publishes them in its fourth section.
Why did this
neglect happen? I think that so-called traditional Marxism treated Marx’s
materialist project as a closed dialectical system that explains everything in
the universe, including human history and nature. In this sense, Marxists did
not pay enough attention to his economic manuscripts and even less to his notebooks,
which document the incomplete character of Marx’s “Capital.”
Of course, there were Marxists who
rejected this omnipotent reading. They are known today under the banner of
“Western Marxism.” When they rejected traditional Marxism, however, they harshly
reproached Engels as the misleading founder of traditional Marxism, who wrongly
expanded Marx’s dialectical critique of capitalist society to the scientific
system of the universe. Consequently, when Western Marxists expelled Engels and
his dialectics of nature, they also excluded the sphere of nature and natural
sciences from their analysis. Consequently, Marx’s serious engagement with
natural sciences was ignored by both traditional and Western Marxists.
But today, no one really believes in
this all-encompassing omnipotence of Marx’s theory, and the “MEGA” makes Marx’s
engagement with natural sciences clearly visible. Thus, we need to find an
alternative approach to Marx’s texts, and it is a chance to utilize the
openness of Marx’s project in a productive way with new materials. In other
words, by looking at his economic manuscripts as well as his notebook on
natural sciences, we can learn from Marx how to develop ecological critique of
capitalism in the 21st century. This is an urgent practical and theoretical
task for today’s left, as humans are now facing a serious global ecological
crisis under neoliberal capitalism.
Your book is
dedicated to rescuing Marx’s ecological critique of capitalism, continuing the
work undertaken by ecosocialists like Paul Burkett and John Bellamy Foster. Why
do you think Marx’s ecological analysis is so important to the left and to
environmentalists today?
Yes, my approach is a clear
continuation of the “metabolic rift” theory advocated by Foster and Burkett,
and one of the aims of my book is to defend the concept of metabolic rift
against recent criticism raised by Jason W. Moore. It is quite apparent today
that mass production and consumption under capitalism has tremendous influence
upon global landscape and causes ecological crisis. Marxist theory thus also
needs to respond to the situation with a clear practical demand to envision a
sustainable society beyond capitalism. Capitalism and material conditions for
sustainable production are incompatible. This is the basic insight of
“ecosocialism.”
I think Naomi Klein’s “This Changes
Everything” has provided a very convincing and concrete analysis of how the
regeneration of the Marxist idea of metabolic rift can open up new imagination
for an ecosocialist project in the 21st century. She shows that such radical
movements are already emerging, and their goals are actually worth striving
for. As she argues, it is necessary to reduce a large amount of carbon emission
every year starting from now on in industrial countries, if increase of average
global temperature in 2100 should be contained within 2 degrees Celsius. But it
is not possible for capitalist global elites and companies to accept this
demand because they know that such project is incompatible with necessary
conditions of capital accumulation.
This is why the Paris agreement is
insufficient to achieve the required reduction of carbon emissions, but Trump
cannot accept even that level of carbon reduction. We have been too often
witnessing global elites’ total incompetence to take any serious measure
against climate change in the last decades. We should realize that the problem
is not simply neoliberalism but capitalism as such. This is why Klein also now
clearly advocates ecosocialism, “a new form of democratic eco-socialism, with
the humility to learn from Indigenous teachings about the duties to future
generations and the interconnection of all of life, appears to be humanity’s
best shot at collective survival.” The antagonism between red and green needs
to be dissolved.
The first
half of your book focuses on Marx’s idea of a metabolism between human beings
and nature. Can you tell us about how ecosocialists are applying the theory of
metabolic rift to the various ecological crises we are currently witnessing?
How does Marx’s theory differ from other strains of ecological theory?
Marx clearly and critically recognized
the destructive power of capital and argued that disruptions in the universal
metabolism of nature inevitably undermine material conditions for free and
sustainable human development. The robbery character inherent to the capitalist
development of productive forces does not bring about progress that leads to
the future society. Marx attempted to analyze how the logic of capital diverges
from the eternal natural cycle and ultimately causes various disharmonies in
the metabolic interaction between humans and nature. Famously enough, he
analyzed this point with reference to Justus von Liebig’s critique of modern
“robbery agriculture (“Raubbau”),” which takes as much nutrition as possible
from the soil without returning it. Robbery agriculture is driven by profit
maximization, which is simply incompatible with the material conditions of the
soil for sustainable production. Thus, there emerges a grave gap between the logic
of capital’s valorization and that of nature’s metabolism, which creates
“metabolic rifts” in human interaction with the environment.
Though Marx in “Capital” mainly
discusses this problem of metabolic rift in relation to soil exhaustion, it is
not at all necessary to limit the scope to it. In fact, Marx himself also tried
to apply this theoretical concept to various issues in his late years, such as
deforestation and stock farming. Therefore, Marx would be happy to see that
today there are various attempts to apply this theoretical framework as a tool
to analyze ongoing environmental crisis. To name a few, Longo’s marine ecology,
Ryan Gunderson’s livestock agribusiness, as well as Del Weston’s climate change
are excellent examples for ecosocialist application of Marx’s theory of
metabolic rift.
One obvious difference between the
ecosocialist approach and that of other strands of ecological theory is the
insight that as long as the capitalist system persists, there is an inevitable
tendency toward the degradation of material conditions of production. In other
words, the market cannot function as a good mediator for the sustainable
production in contrast to the persistent liberal belief that green capitalism
is somehow possible in the near future. The time left for us is very short.
Under these conditions, liberal’s hope that carbon trade or other market
transactions can solve climate change only functions as an ideological tool to
distract us from confronting the real danger and threat, as if the market could
automatically solve the problem without our conscious engagement to radically
change the existing mode of production. Liberals are very dangerous in this
sense.
The second
part of your book focuses on Marx’s view of the possibilities of achieving “rational
agriculture” under capitalism and how that view changed over time as he
continued his research. Did Marx conclude that the ecological destruction
caused by capitalism cannot be resolved within the limits of capitalism?
Young Marx was still quite optimistic
about the capitalist development of technologies and natural sciences. Thus, he
thought that it would prepare conditions for sustainable agriculture in
socialism. However, as he was writing “Capital,” he started to emphasize that
the main aim of capitalist production is not sustainable production but the
valorization of capital. Marx realized that, ultimately, it does not matter
even if a large part of the planet becomes unsuitable for life, as long as
capital accumulation is still possible. Correspondingly, Marx realized that
technological development is organized as “productive forces of capital,” which
lead to the full realization of negative aspects of technologies, so they
cannot function as a material foundation for socialist society.
The problem is discernible in the fact
that capital can profit even from environmental disaster. This tendency is
clearly visible in what neoliberal “disaster capitalism” has done in the last
decades, as Klein documents in detail. If this is the case, then it is wrong to
assume that the end of cheap nature would impose a great difficulty on the
capital accumulation, as James O’Connor indicated with his theory of the
“second contradiction of capital.” Consequently, capital can actually continue
to make profit more from the current ecological crisis by inventing new
business opportunities, such as geoengineering, GMOs, carbon trade and
insurances for natural disasters. Thus, natural limits do not lead to the
collapse of the capitalist system. It can keep going even beyond those limits,
but the current level of civilization cannot exist beyond a certain limit. This
is why a serious engagement with global warming simultaneously requires a
conscious struggle against capitalism.
You point out
that, toward the end of his life, Marx became aware of the danger of climate
change as a result of society’s irrational management of nature—an incredible
insight given that he was writing a century and a half ago. How did Marx
understand climate change?
Foster argues that Marx might have
attended John Tyndall’s lecture on the greenhouse effect, so he knew about the
cause of today’s global warming. My argument is somewhat different, as there is
no direct evidence to prove Marx’s familiarity with this topic. Rather, I
examined his notebook on Carl Fraas’s “Climate and Plant World over Time,”
which Marx read in the beginning of 1868. The book discusses climate change, as
a result not of greenhouse gas emissions but of excessive deforestation, which
changes the local air circulation and precipitation. Fraas’s analysis expanded
Marx’s interest in the robbery character of capitalist production beyond soil
exhaustion, and in some sense, he evaluated Fraas’s theory even more than
Liebig’s.
Even if Marx did not know the exact
causes of today’s global warming, it is not a major deficit because Marx did
not claim to have explained everything. Until the last moment of his life, he
was very eager to integrate new findings in the natural sciences into his
analysis of metabolic rifts. He was unable to fully achieve this aim, and
“Capital” remained unfinished. But his critique of political economy is elastic
enough to incorporate recent scientific progress. Since his critique of
metabolic rift provides a methodological foundation to a critical analysis of
the current global ecological crisis, it is our task today to substantiate and
update Marx’s ecology for the 21st century by developing the synthetic analysis
of political economy and natural sciences as a radical critique of capitalism.
This is exactly what people like Brett Clark and Richard York as well as other
people already mentioned are conducting now.
Using the
example of the exhaustion of Irish soil due to British colonialism, Marx showed
how the expansion of capital around the world is directly linked to ecological
crisis in the colonial countries. What lessons can we draw from this example,
and what does it tell us about overcoming the worldwide ecological crises
today, which are far greater in scale?
In the key passage to the concept of
the metabolic rift, Marx wrote that the capitalist mode of production “produces
conditions that provoke an irreparable rift in the interdependent process between
social metabolism and natural metabolism prescribed by the natural laws of the
soil. The result of this is a squandering of the vitality of the soil, and
trade carries this devastation far beyond the bounds of a single country
(Liebig).” With an expansion of capitalist accumulation, the metabolic rift
becomes a global issue.
Marx’s theory proves correct, as this
is exactly what we are witnessing today, especially with climate change. As I
said, climate change will not put an end to the regime of capital. In any case,
capitalism is much more elastic in that this social system is likely to survive
and continue to accumulate capital even if ecological crisis deepens to destroy
the entire planet and to produce a mass environmental proletariat all over the
world. Rich people would probably survive, while the poor are much more
vulnerable to climate change, even though they are much less responsible for
the crisis than the rich. The poor do not possess effective technological and
financial means to protect themselves from the catastrophic consequences of
climate change to come. Fighting for climate justice clearly includes a
component of class struggle, as was the case in British colonialism in Ireland
and India.
While climate change could change
everything about our life, changing climate change will change capitalism. This
is how ecosocialism comprehends ecological crisis and metabolic rifts as the
central contradiction of capitalism. Marx was one of the first ecosocialists,
since he recognized this point when he found a “socialist tendency” in Carl
Fraas’s warning against excessive deforestation and climate change. Thus, to
overcome alienation from nature is a central task for both red and green, which
can be realized only beyond capitalism, and not within “green capitalism.”
Kohei Saito is an associate professor
of political economy at Osaka University and author of “Karl Marx’s
Ecosocialism,” winner of the 2018 Deutscher Memorial Prize. He is also an
editor of the Marx-Engels-Gesamtausgabe (MEGA), which includes many of Marx’s
previously unpublished notebooks on natural science.
Astounding! In my own reading of Capital I had also noticed an ecological motif, and had concluded to myself that Marx recognized a major contradiction between capitalist accumulation and the sustainability of nature. I'm so glad that this realization is being picked up in academic circles as well! Let's keep expanding his theories to the natural sciences and we will have a powerful weapon of knowledge with which to arm the working class.
ReplyDeleteRecently finished reading 'Karl Marx’s Ecosocialism'. A tour de force of clarity. Most important book on Marxism and its contemporary relevance in decades.
ReplyDeleteIt is good to see that more traditional Marxist's are taking ecological issues on board. The primary purpose of this blog is to bring red and green together.
ReplyDelete