Written by Timothée
Parrique and Giorgos Kallis and first published at Brave New Europe
Notable
(eco)socialists have recently criticized the idea of degrowth 1.
Here we want to argue that such criticism is misplaced. Growth is a problem
over and above capitalism. A sustainable eco-socialism should reject any
association with the ideology and terminology of growth. 21st century
socialists should start thinking how we can plan for societies that prosper
without growth. Like it not, growth is bound to come to an end, the question is
how; and whether this will happen soon or too late to avert planetary
disasters.
Any form of
endless growth is ecologically unsustainable
The typical socialist response to degrowth is that it is capitalism, and capitalist growth, that are the problem, not economic growth. But here’s the thing: no economic growth can be sustainable. An increase in material living standards will require, well, more materials. This is independent of whether the economy at stake is capitalist, socialist, anarchist, or primitive.
Growth in the material standard of living
requires growth in the extraction of materials and the excretion of pollution
(growth in the standard of living in general does not; we discuss this below).
Result: as of today – and very likely tomorrow as well – economic
growth strongly
correlates with energy and material use, at the global level
which is the only one that shows the full picture in a globalised economy.
Leading Marxist theorist David Harvey calls the idea of compound growth the madness of economic reason, and the most lethal of capitalism’s lethal contradictions (which makes us wonder why would socialists spend their time trying to salvage this madness). To see how mad it is, consider the following.
An innocent 3% growth
each year, means a doubling of the economy every 24 years, some ten times bigger
by the end of the century, quickly growing to an infinite size. Substitute the
economy with whatever you like (‘energy’, ‘water’, ‘bicycles’, ‘massages’). The
idea of infinity is pure madness, full stop. It is the generalisation of the
logic of individual capitalists who expect to pocket their 3-5% return every
year, rain or shine. But it is not something that a society can sustain for
long.
Some socialists dream of a Fully Automated Luxury Communism where new technologies enable the absolute decoupling of economic output from the environment. So far, this has not happened, not even close, and there are doubts as to whether the future holds better prospects. Like it or not, economies too have to obey the laws of physics.
For example, thermodynamics tells us
that energy can neither be created nor destroyed but only transformed, and that
its quality moves inexorably towards a less usable or useful state. This means
there is no silver-bullet technology that can make an increase in the material
standard of living immaterial – economy is fundamentally embedded within
ecology.
Of course, certain activities are more nature-intensive than others; and so potentially these could grow for a longer period without disrupting the biosphere. For example, fossil fuels are more disruptive than solar energy. But that does not mean solar energy opens the door to boundless growth. A better organisation of production and new technologies can increase productivity and lead to a relative decoupling with less resources used per product – e.g. more efficient solar panels.
But if the quantity of solar panels increases at a compound rate
without limit, it will, one day, start to put pressure on either resource
availability or lead to ecological damage. In other words, nothing material can
be infinite, regardless of whether the economy is capitalist, socialist, or
anything else in between.
Furthermore, it
is one thing to decarbonise with renewable energies an energy system at its
current size, or one fifth of it (a reduction in energy use which studies show
is feasible with existing sufficiency and efficiency measures), and another to
decarbonise a system that has grown ten times bigger by the end of the century
(remember 3% growth per year).
Our suggestion: democratic socialist planning would have to consider the constraining requirement of a degrowth use of energy and materials. This is not too much of a problem because, as we will soon argue, many of the activities that are heavy in energy and materials today do not need to exist under socialism.
There is
too much superfluous activity under capitalism, which serves nothing else but
the need of capitalists to extract surplus value and make profits. The goal
instead should be socialism
without growth, a sustainable socialism – an
economic system that manages to satisfy the needs of its people without
clinging to capitalist ideas of constant expansion and without of course
overshooting planetary limits.
Growth
requires accumulation and accumulation comes with exploitation
There is another problem. In the same way that economic growth is facing ecological limits, it is also facing social ones. Capitalists make a profit exploiting wage earners (surplus value in Marxist terms), and also exploiting the unpaid work of an array of people, especially women doing unpaid care and housework, who ensure the socio-natural reproduction of the work force for free.
Capital also relies on ‘free gifts of nature’ (free only from its
perspective), which alongside unpaid care and housework keep the price of means
of production and labour power cheap, allowing capital to squeeze surplus
value. In effect, economic growth under capitalism often occurs at the
expense of the social fabric, as it relies on systematic exploitation and cost
shifting.
By not accounting for reproduction factors, such as rest, affection, caring, security, and the providing of sustenance, production can too easily lead to their depletion. For example, working full-time leaves little time for activities that are unpaid such as those which are key for social reproduction. As production increases, it will stretch the capacity for a society to reproduce its livelihood.
Continued unabated, this accumulation via social deterioration
comes to erode factors of reproduction that are crucial for all forms of
production. Like a snake biting its own tail, economic growth is limited
because it is inevitably based on the unsustainable exploitation of reproductive
labour and ecosystem provisioning.
If socialism
means the end of exploitation, it also means the end of endless accumulation.
Again: this is socialism without growth. A genuine socialist
economy would not exploit the work or resources of other economies; it would
share care work evenly, rotate unpleasant tasks and compensate care workers
with their dues for their reproductive work. With no one – humans and
non-humans – being exploited, the economy would simply produce the goods and
services it needs, channelling productivity gains into more free time.
Some socialists try to square the circle here, when they argue that socialism would be able to both end exploitation, and grow the economy as much or even more than capitalism. Sorry, but this is pure fantasy. If socialist production has to pay for the true labour time of producers, and for the true time necessary for ecosystems to recover and recuperate, or if human labour time has to be expended instead of ‘free gifts of nature’ that will be left unexploited, then there will be less surplus, and less surplus can only mean less growth of output.
A genuine socialism will also be democratic, one would like to think.
True democracy slows things down (those participating in the assemblies of
their local cooperatives know what we’re talking about). Again to think that
all this slowing down will lead to acceleration and not deceleration of
production is truly wishful thinking.
Use values
do not grow
The good news
is that we can have prosperity without growth. In fact, it has been shown
empirically that the main indicators of living standards, including well-being,
health, and education, cease to increase after a certain threshold of output is
reached – some call it the Well-being
Turning Point. For example, Portugal has significantly better
social outcomes than the United States, with
65% less GDP per capita. This is because welfare depends on the
satisfaction of actual use values, expressing human needs, and not
on the endless accumulation of money.
Socialists know
this well: GDP is not a measure of use values, but one of exchange
values. The indicator does
not distinguish between desirable and undesirable activities. On top of that,
it ignores all that is non-monetary (including nature and unpaid work),
neglects the value of intangible wealth, and does not account for inequality.
What GDP measures is the welfare of capitalism, not people.
Of course, the
provision of certain useful goods and services must increase and should
increase under socialism. However, let us not talk about “growth” for
improvements in things like health, mobility, or education. These are not
quantitative goals but qualitative ones. Children might need a freer and more
holistic, polytechnic education. This requires a finite number of school
buildings, teachers, and pens. Patients may need more human contact and care by
their doctors; what they need is not an infinitely increasing compound rate of
care, but just enough to feel better. People who do not have
bikes need one bike – not a yearly increase of 3% in the
production of bikes, forever.
The point is that use values do not grow at a compound rate. Fundamental human needs like subsistence, protection, freedom, or identity can all be understood as thresholds of sufficiency: enough food to be healthy, enough living space to be happy, enough means of mobility to feel free, etc. The story of endless consumption to match endless needs is a capitalist discourse, created precisely to legitimate accumulation for the elite.
And this is the central
argument of degrowth:
standards of living can improve without growth by redistributing and sharing
wealth, doing away with artificial desires and the superfluous goods and
appropriation of our time destined to the making of profit, and by shifting
from valuing material goods to valuing relations. There is already enough for
everyone to have a decent share – if the pie cannot grow, then it is time to
share it more evenly.
Conclusions:
Degrowth is as anti-capitalist as it gets
The ideology
of growth has become the powerhouse of modern capitalism and
we do not understand why some socialists are reluctant to join the battle
against a phenomenon that is socially divisive and ecologically unsustainable.
A socialism without growth but with well-being. Socialism and degrowth are two of the most powerful concepts we have to criticise capitalism and open-up different futures.
As is evident
by now, we do use the C-word, a lot. Certain Marxist commentators have accused
degrowth of never explicitly questioning capitalism. Phillips
(2015) depicts degrowth as a “small-scale steady-state
capitalism.” The degrowth project some would think resembles the film Downsizing (2017),
where exuberant consumerism is made environmentally possible by shrinking
people down to a few centimetres.
So, let us be
clear: degrowth is not miniature capitalism with tiny corporations, tiny
speculative financial instruments, and tiny free trade agreements. It is not
austerity within capitalism. It is an alternative system of provision
altogether – not just smaller and slower, but different.
You may ask why focus on growth and not just capitalism? Well, try to compare the occurrence of “economic growth” versus “capital accumulation” in the news. As Gareth Dale has forcefully argued, economic growth is the ideology that has turned the specific interest of capital to grow (for returns, and for keeping social peace) into a generalized social objective assimilated by the population.
This is not an
ideology that will go away by refusing to confront it or beautifying it with
nice adjectives. The fact that this ideology survived even the end of
capitalism (or at least of a certain type of capitalism) in ex-socialist
regimes should give pause for thought. Socialists who defend growth must also
think twice whether they are redwashing capital, redressing the dreams that
capitalism sells as socialist dreams.
Growth is the
child of capitalism, but the child grew up and took over the head of the
family. Capitalism’s interest in accumulation is promoted and legitimised
through – and in the name of – “growth.” The critique of growth is the most
fundamental critique of capitalism – one that criticises not only the means
capitalism uses but the very ends it sells. This makes degrowth and
(eco)socialism natural allies, not adversaries.
1 Most
recently, “Ecosocialism
and/or Degrowth?” by Michael Löwy (Oct. 2020), the “IMT
theses on the climate crisis” published on the website In Defence
of Marxism (Jun. 2020), and the lecture in “Degrowth and
neo-Malthusianism: A socialist response” (Oct. 2020) by Olivia
Rickson. And ‘How much stuff is just enough’ by Leigh Phillips at the Monde
Diplomatique (https://mondediplo.com/2021/02/11degrowth).
Giorgos
Kallis is an environmental scientist working on ecological economics, political
ecology, and water policy. He teaches political ecology and ecological
economics at the Autonomous University of Barcelona and recently co-edited the
book “The
Case for Degrowth”
Timothée Parrique holds a PhD in economics from the Centre d’Études et de Recherches sur le Développement (University of Clermont Auvergne, France) and the Stockholm Resilience Centre (Stockholm University, Sweden)
i would not argue against the thrust of this article; indeed it is music to my eyes.
ReplyDeleteBut we should not underestimate the challenge of convincing the majority of the public that a society based on needs not wants is a desirable goal; the allure of 'more' (size of home, number of cars/gadgets/new clothes/huge steaks/multiple holiday flights etc ) seems to be powerful.
I think you are right Jay, that is why I written elsewhere on this blog, of the need for a profound cultural change in what we value. Only then will change come.
DeleteI suspect that, once the pandemic's restrictions subside in the UK, we'll see a festival of consumption that dwarfs all previous records, along with the fossil fuels and emissions to match. I hope not.
ReplyDeleteYou are probably right.
DeleteIf economic growth simply means increasing the GDP/GNP we can agree it is very problematic, and growth driven by fossil capitalism is surely destructive. But growth in the economy needs to be unpacked even under capitalism. A global GND will mean real growth in meeting human and nature's needs. See my critique at: http://www.globalecosocialistnetwork.net/2020/12/17/a-critique-of-degrowth-an-ecosocialist-alternative/. This article has references that you can explore, including our earlier critique of Kallis’ CNS paper on the same theme. I invite critique: dschwartzman@gmail.com.
ReplyDeleteBest wishes,
David Schwartzman
My latest book: The Global Solar Commons, the Future That is Still Possible: A Guide for 21st Century Activists;
Confronting the current deep crisis and mapping out a path to this future
Free download at: https://www.theearthisnotforsale.org/solarcommons.pdf
More readable for activists than our deeply documented more technical The Earth is Not for Sale.
Donations of any amount welcome suggested to the Green Eco-Socialist Network, https://eco-socialism.org/join-contribute/
Review: https://washingtonsocialist.mdcdsa.org/ws-articles/20-11-global-commons-solar-energy
How do de-growthers correlate their ideas with the fact that millions upon millions of people around the world do not have piped potable water, effective sewerage systems, reliable (if any) electricity, a decent dwelling and good communications; in short, a large proportion of the world's population do not enjoy a civilised minimum existence?
ReplyDeleteTo provide a civilised minimum existence would require a hefty use of resources, building materials such as concrete, metals, plastics, timber, all of which would mean a big increase in production, not de-growth minimalisation. A socialist society would be able to save a lot by way of more efficient production and diverting resources from 'conspicuous consumption' and anti-social production (military, etc) to socially useful production. But I'm sure that providing the world's population with what they deserve can't be done by reducing production.
Maybe I'm old-fashioned, but I can't see socialism ever being a reality when human beings still have to struggle to survive and don't enjoy a life at a level of a civilised minimum.
Dr Paul
That is what ecosocialism would provide, it is not just eco, but socialist too.
DeleteI don't disagree with this at all. I do struggle with transition though. I live in a council flat in the Square Mile. Population 7-8,000. Pre Covid population of commuters 500,000 M-F
ReplyDeleteConcrete and Steel and Glass of offices. How do we transition in a practical sense let alone deal with the 900 year old rule of the Corporation of the City of London